Real convergence and integration

Aurel IANCU
Romanian Academy
National Institute For Economic Research
Street Av. Radu Beller, No. 19, sect. 1, Bucharest, Romania
[email protected]

Abstract. The study is based on the critical observations that competitive market forces alone are not able to assure convergence with the developed countries. These observations are grounded on the results of the computation of the marginal rate of return to capital (which contradict the neoclassical model hypotheses), as well as on the real process of polarisation of the economic activities, taking place worldwide and in accordance with the law of competition. Unlike those who trust the perfect competitive market virtues, the EU’s economic policy is realistic as it is based on the harmonisation of the market forces with an economic policy based on the principle of cohesion, which supports, by means of economic levers, the less developed regions and member countries. This paper deals with the evolution of the EU cohesion funds, as well as with the results of convergence.
Key words: Neoclassical model, marginal rate of return on capital, polarisation, convergence, divergence, cohesion, cohesion funds, structural funds, variation coefficient.
JEL: F02, F15, O57, P37

Economists wonder if real economy convergence can actually be achieved only in a competitive market according to the neoclassical models. In this respect, extensive studies and models have been conducted. Considering the way the determinants and trends of real convergence are approached, the studies and models may be divided into three categories:
The first one views real convergence as a natural process, based exclusively on the market forces, in accordance with which the convergence process is surer and faster as the market is larger, more functional, less distorted.
The second one denies that, in the present competitive market, there is an actual real convergence between the poor and the rich countries, but accepts the existence of the tendency of polarisation or deepening of the divergences and inequalities between the centre and the periphery.
The third one considers that real convergence is necessary and possible in a competitive market, provided that economic policies are implemented to compensate for the negative effects of the inequalities or divergences, until the economic systems reach maturity or the so-called critical mass to support the self-sufficiency of the real convergence process.
Further, we make some critical comments and present some arguments in support of the alternatives that are closer to the real needs and opportunities the Romanian economy to achieve convergence with the EU real economy.

1. Convergence through the functional competitive market forces
The first way to perceive real convergence exclusively by the market forces is the neoclassical growth theory. Assuming that the economic outcome (GDP per capita) is ensured by the contribution of several production factors (capital, labour, natural resources, technological progress), the neoclassical model advances the fundamental hypothesis that growth depends on the features of the rate of return on capital, which generally tends to decrease in relation to the economic growth. For a certain increase in capital, the outcome increase is less than proportional. More exactly, at the same saving (investment) rate, the marginal rate of return on capital decreases, so that poor countries, with a low amount of capital per capita, attain higher rates of return to capital than those of rich countries with a considerably higher amount of capital per capita.
According to the neoclassical model, the higher rate of return on capital achieved by the poor countries/regions as against the rich countries/regions (if the other conditions are comparable) ensure the long-term convergent economic growth. This postulate is explained by many authors (based on the Solow’s model) taking into account the assumption of equal saving rates (accumulation), population/employed population growth, capital depreciation, technological progress, etc. for all categories of countries. This is the only way that all countries, on different initial development levels, may reach the convergence or equilibrium state by economic growth rates higher in the poor countries than in the rich ones.
According to the neoclassical school, many economists consider that the competition intensification by the establishment and enlargement of the European internal market and integration would have a positive impact and offer opportunities to the countries and regions for diminishing the development and per capita income disparities in order to achieve real convergence. Only action on a larger scale of the competitive internal market forces in the EU, free of any interventionist (protectionist) policy, could guarantee the real convergence of the EU countries and regions.
The free movement of the production factors among the European countries and regions, especially through capital market integration and FDI, is an important way to achieve real convergence.
The less developed countries and regions are characterized by capital scarcity and low saving capability, due to the low income per capita. This means that those territorial entities offer opportunities for development and attract available capital from the countries rich in capital, whose companies are eager to penetrate a large safe and profitable market. After the accession, the capital inflows as investments increased. Among them, the foreign direct investments became the most important means of attracting various intangible resources, such as technology, know-how, expertise, managerial experience, etc. Foreign direct investments have clearer advantages, if compared with financial investments. But their presence in a country or region is dependent on the following requirements: a) sufficient infrastructure of high quality; b) low transaction costs (similar to those in agglomerated areas); c) abundant and cheap local resources (their low cost may compensate for the additional transaction cost, due to the scarce infrastructure); d) possibility to make horizontal investments based on scale economies, showing a significant dispersion of the production units among countries and regions, as close to the potential clients as possible.
To make the markets of the new EU countries perfectly compatible and competitive, the European Commission implements a systematic policy for the elimination of the non-competitive elements from the market by banning state aid, protectionist actions and other elements that may cause distortions of the single market and national markets.
Moreover, it is quite obvious that many economic reform measures taken by the CEE countries as well as the implementation of the Community acquis and the institutional improvement are aimed at creating a functional competitive market within every national economy and the Community market.
Some economists and international financial institutions still believe that an enlarged and functional market as well as the profound economic integration require the existence of strong mechanisms that automatically lead to real convergence, without any policy in support of such convergence. The implementation of such policies means, in their opinion, many other distortions of the market.
It is quite obvious that such opinions are expressed by the supporters of the neoclassical model, as they think that only the market forces free of any intervention may set in motion efficiently the mechanisms that enable the poor countries to recover the delays by higher growth rates than those of developed countries.
Although the reasoning based on the hypothesis of decreasing rate of return and the hypothesis of perfect competition is logically correct, facts contradict such opinions. On the one hand, poor countries lack the necessary economic, scientific, technological and financial power to cope with competition, which explains, to some extent, the reverse trend, that is widening the gap (divergence) between the poor and the rich countries, and not diminishing it. On the other hand, one should not ignore the overall natural trend of clustering or polarisation of the economic activities at different (national, regional or sub-regional) levels, which might become a major obstacle to convergence.

2. The neoclassical model shortcomings and new approaches
The empirical research done in the last two decades to check the validity of the neoclassical model of convergent growth has not been as relevant as expected. To clarify this crucial problem, we intend to check the veracity of the assumption concerning the existence of decreasing rate of return on capital, illustrated by the existence or non-existence of the correlation between the marginal rate of return of the physical capital (the rate of return of investment in physical capital) and the country’s development level (GDP per capita). Consequently we consider the following two indicators:
(i) Rate of return of gross investment in capital (RGI) based on the ratio:
ΔGDP per capita, representing thr GDP per capita growth in 2004,
as against the previous year (2003) expressed in PPP – USD
RGI = The amount of gross investment in capital per capita in 2003
(ii) Per capita Gross Domestic Product expressed in PPP-USD in 2003.
Computing these two indicators, on a total number of 180 countries and a number of groups of countries at different development level, including the group of the 24 EU member countries, and correlating the rate of return with the GDP per capita, the results are presented in the graphs in Figures 1-6, in which we noted: on the horizontal, the GDP/capita in 2003 and on the vertical, the rate of return of gross investment, for each of the two alternative computations.

Figure 1: The rate of return to the gross investment (RRGI) by the development level of the economies
Source: Based on UN statistical data.
Figure 2: The rate of return to the gross investment (RRGI) of the countries with a GDP
per capita of 550-2500 USD-PPP
Source: Based on UN statistical data.
Figure 3: The rate of return to the gross investment (RRGI) of the countries
with a GDP per capita of 2501-7000 USD-PPP Source: Based on UN statistical data.
Source: Based on UN statistical data.
Figure 4: The rate of return to the gross investment (RRGI) of the countries
with a GDP per capita of 7001-15000 USD-PPP
Source: Based on UN statistical data.
Figure 5: The rate of return to the gross investment (RRGI) of the countries
with a GDP per capita of 15001- 40000 USD-PPP
Source: Based on UN statistical data.
Figure 6: The rate of return to the gross investment (RRGI) of the EU member countries
Source: Based on UN statistical data.

The graphic presentation in fig. 1-5 do not show any downward trends of the marginal rate of returns to capital. The trends are rather constant. The slight downward trend in the EU countries (fig. 6) could be explained by the cohesion policy of the EU.
The existence of the increasing or constant rate of return means, according to the neoclassical model, a condition towards divergence or widening the gap among countries. Some clarifications and explicit analyses (beyond the restrictive postulates required by this type of too simplified a model) concerning the definition of the production factors and the interpretation of the economic mechanism closer to reality, as a same of convergence or divergence, are brought by the endogenous theory.
Dividing the capital factor into the three components – physical capital, human capital and stock of knowledge – and considering that these components do not come from outside, but represent accumulations after the input within the system, we may identify which factors have additional effects in relation to the input, in what proportion and, finally, which category of countries stimulate the factors through the allocated inputs and which factors produce the greatest results.
Rejecting the old hypothesis concerning the decreasing rate of return on capital and other unverifiable constraints, the new theory concentrates on types of models able to include the effects caused within the system by major production factors – human capital, productive knowledge stock, etc. – as well as types of models able to determine the real causes and mechanisms of the long-term disparities (using the cross-section analysis or long time series), by correlating the growth rate of the production and the per capita income on the national or/and regional level with economic, social and political variables which become either the engine or the brake of growth.
The new theory of convergence is based on the operational character of the effects of the intangible factors (including the economic policy factors). These effects (called “spillovers”) spill over the economy in a special way, that is, over other entities, than their direct producers. The effects exceed the input necessary for their production or their remuneration amount.
Usually, the intangible factors (knowledge, professional abilities or skills, information, innovation, know-how, etc.) are embodied in tangible production factors, and their outputs are spilled over. Spillovers may occur during the investment in physical capital (Arrow, 1962), in human capital (Lucas, 1988) or in both types of investment (Romer, 1986). According to Romer, if the spillovers are strong, the private marginal product of the physical and human capital may stay permanently above the discount rate (Romer, 1986; Thirlwall, 2001). Growth may be supported by continuous accumulation (investment), which generates positive spillovers (Grossman and Helpman, 1994), associated with the formation of the human capital (education and training or qualification) and with the Research, development and innovation (RD&I), thus preventing the diminution of the rate of return to capital or the increase in the capital-output ratio.

3. Divergence and polarisation – Lasting effects of the competitive market forces
The empirical research for testing the validity of the neoclassical model has demonstrated that, in most cases, neither the hypothesis concerning the decreasing rate of return to capital, nor the real convergence between the poor and the rich countries (regions) is confirmed. It is impossible to explain the international discrepancy in the present development level only by making reference to the initial difference in factor endowment (Thirlwall, 2001). What actually counts is stimulating the development of the new factors (human capital and knowledge stock) and their increasing contribution to economic growth, detecting possible obstacles to growth in the poor countries and, finally, testing whether the mechanisms causing the inequality between the developed countries and the poor ones may last or not.
The theoretical contribution made by Perroux, Myrdal, Prebisch, etc. has changed the way of explaining real convergence and decisively influenced the direction of the economic policy for the European construction, beginning with the drafting of the Rome Treaty. Although not always analytically rigorous, the new economic notions included in the scientific circuit, such as attraction poles, clusters, centre-periphery, flows of complementary factors, positive spillovers, etc., have broadened the horizon of the debates and the understanding of the processes taking place in the real economy, and the research area concerning the economic policy.
The above notions and the concept of circular cumulative cause of the economic processes help us explain the increasing international difference in the development level as against the similar initial conditions. The movement of capital, the human capital and labour migration, the goods and services exchange perpetuate and even worsen international and regional development inequalities. By means of the free trade mechanisms (i.e., free of tariff and non-tariff barriers), the less developed countries, which lack the human capital and the scientific and technological capability, have to specialize in the production of mostly primary goods characterized by an inelastic or almost inelastic demand in relation to price and income.
What causes the increasing inequality between countries is the tendency of interregional and international polarisation (agglomeration), especially in the context of the economic and monetary integration. As there are no barriers to the movement of goods, services and production factors, some countries and regions form strong poles of attraction and cause imbalances between countries showing important differences in the income per capita. The developed countries and regions endowed with factors become poles of attraction that absorb increasing amounts of high quality labour and capital from the less developed countries.
Even if during the accession process the countries make major efforts to support the economic and institutional reforms and attempts to achieve a stable development equilibrium, in real life there is a natural trend with an universal character towards the polarisation of the processes, which in turn causes the broadening of the gap between the development levels of the countries and regions. Myrdal claims that the economic and social forces alike tend towards equilibrium and that the economic theory hypotheses according to which disequilibrium situations tend towards equilibrium are false (Myrdal, 1957; Thirlwall, 2001). If it were not true, then how could one explain the international differences in the standard of living? Unable to answer this question, Myrdal replaces the stable equilibrium hypothesis with what he calls the circular cumulative causation hypothesis or, briefly speaking, the cumulative causation hypothesis. This hypothesis helps us explain why the international and interregional differences in the development level may persist and increase in time.
Myrdal’s hypothesis is based on a multiplier-accelerator mechanism, which causes the income to rise at higher rates in the so-called favoured – more developed – countries and regions, which are endowed with modern infrastructure, gain scientific and technological ascendancy and enjoy physical and human capital inflows, as well as scientific and technological inflows; consequently, they become more attractive for their capital and labour than the less developed areas. The free trade in goods and services and the full freedom of movement of the production factors among countries and regions showing great differences in the development level causes increasing polarisation: on the one hand, countries and regions that become richer, enjoy a significant economic growth and show attractiveness to the high-skilled production factors and, on the other hand, countries and regions characterized by stagnation and economic decline, obsolete and non-attractive infrastructure, decreasing income and taxation levels, that is, limited demand for goods and services.
Under these circumstances, there cannot be any economic convergence. The approaches and analyses initiated by Myrdal, Prebisch, Seers, etc. have led to an influent trend, based on the concept of divergence, which points out the process of polarisation and the divergence between the centre and the periphery.
This trend of thought brings influence to bear upon the following levels:
the practical one, reflected in the European construction projects by the adoption of some tools of the European economic policy;
the analytical one, strongly reflected in two directions:
re-thinking the construction and interpretation of economic growth, by returning to the economic and social realities (it concerns the development of endogenous models and the econometric testing);
new approaches to the geographic (regional) economy, taking into account real processes, such as: regional disparities, development agglomerations or poles, role of infrastructure, transaction costs.

4. Cohesion – An important tool in support of the real convergence within the EU
The chance that the poor national economies advance towards convergence within an enlarged and highly competitive single market is illusory. There are some mechanisms that rather stimulate divergence. But there are some other ones that may produce positive effects on the long-term convergence processes, although their success is rather uncertain in the absence of economic policies to support them and to prevent the negative effects. Among the most important mechanisms mentioned by Pelkmans and pointed out by us, one may find the following:
the intraindustrial specialisation of the less developed countries on parts of products and operations, in accordance with the comparative advantage principle, for the capitalisation of the available national (local) resources at small costs;
the integration of the less developed countries into the EU makes them more attractive to foreign capital, and, first, to foreign direct investments, initially within the existing economic clusters and then extended gradually to the periphery territories, along with the infrastructure extension;
the strengthening of the competition to which the products, services, factors and companies from the less developed countries are exposed as the countries accede to the EU, which eliminates the non-competitive local activities and causes dramatic social problems, while such activities are taken over by viable competitive companies;
the integration into a large single market in accordance with the Community acquis eliminates the distortions and the obstacles to development, but does not always stimulate the development of the poor countries and regions.
The impact of the integration on economic growth, in the absence of cohesion policies, does not ensure that the poor countries will reach higher GDP per capita growth rates than the more developed countries, to enable convergence. Unlocking convergence mechanisms by cohesion policies has become one of the EU’s major objectives.
When the Rome Treaty stipulated that “the harmonious development of the economic activities” and “the continuous and balanced expansion” are the first two economic objectives, both the structural divergence and the difference in income per capita between the backward and the advanced members of the Common Market were taken into consideration. To achieve the real convergence in both cases, the Treaty was based implicitly and exclusively on the market mechanisms.
Considering the scarcity of market mechanisms for the recovery of the poor countries and regions, the EU has gradually gained tasks concerning cohesion and solidarity in order to facilitate real convergence by improving the economic performance. The adoption of the cohesion principle was mostly determined by the accession of the countries with a GDP per capita much below the EU average (Greece, Portugal and the CEE countries). The cohesion principle, applied by means of specific tools, is largely used to diminish the disparities in the GDP per capita between countries and regions by improving their performance.
The most important step taken to adopt the principles of cohesion and harmonious development was the explicit inclusion of three economic objectives concerning convergence in the Maastricht Treaty: (1) harmonious and sustainable development of the economic activities; (2) high level of convergence of the economic performance; (3) economic and social cohesion and solidarity of the member states. The objectives (concerning the real convergence of the economic performance through cohesion) were included in the Amsterdam Treaty, with some formal modifications. To apply the above-mentioned principle, two important categories of EU funds were created: structural funds and cohesion funds.
The structural funds are mostly directed to the EU regions with a GDP per capita below 75% of the EU average. The funds are provided: to support the development of the infrastructure in the backward regions; to develop human resources, mainly by training; to enable the private sector development.
The cohesion fund provides support for the EU member countries (with a GDP per capita under 90% of the EU-15 average) to meet the requirements for the European Single Market and the transition to the EMU. Until 2006, cohesion funds were granted to Greece, Ireland, Portugal and Spain. Afterwards, between 2004 and 2006 the countries which joined the EU in 2004 received the total amount of 8.495 billion euros, out of which Poland received almost half. In 2007, Romania and Bulgaria joined the countries receiving cohesion funds. These funds are used to finance directly individual projects on transport infrastructure and environment, provided that they are clearly identified.
The amount provided for the Cohesion Fund increased at a fast pace (see Table 1).

Table 1
Evolution of the Cohesion Fund, 1975-2013

Year

Mil. ECU/euro

Share in EU budget, %

1975

257 (ECU)

4.8

1981

1 540 (ECU)

7.3

1987

3 311 (ECU)

9.1

1992

18 557 (ECU)

25.0

1998

33 461 (ECU)

37.0

2002 (incl. pre-accession assistance)

34 615 (euros)

35.0

2006 UE-25

38 791 (euros)

32.0

2013 UE-27 *

50 960 (euros)

32.0

Source: Helen Wallace, William Wallace and Mark A. Pollack, Elaborarea politicilor în Uniunea Europeană (translation into Romanian of the Policy-making of EU), Ediţia a cincea, Institutul European din România, 2005, p. 205.

The most important transfers to the cohesion countries (in 1989-1999) were the following: Greece received an amount equivalent to 3.5% of the GDP, Portugal 3.3%, Ireland 2.4% and Spain 1.5%.
In 2007-2013, the resources allocated to the cohesion policy (received by the countries with a GDP per capita below 90% of the EU-27 average) will amount to 336.1 billion euros, that is, one-third of the EU total budget and about 4% of the EU GDP. To these resources one should add the structural funds (competitiveness for growth and employment) of 132.77 billion euros, as well as the funds for the preservation and management of the natural resurses of 404.77 billion euros, of which: 301.06 billion euros for agriculture (market expenditure and direct payment).
Since the main objective is the promotion of the development projects in the backward countries and regions, the structural and cohesion funds are essential operational tools that spread the new poles of attraction in order to extend viable businesses to new areas of the recipient cohesion countries by the development of both the physical (tangible) infrastructure and the intangible one, pertaining to the information, training (qualification), knowledge and innovation fields.

5. Evidence concerning the need for cohesion policies and some assessment of the real convergence
Although the development level of the country’s real economy is not a condition for the accession to the EU or a negotiation issue for the accession, the question of catching-up or bridging the gaps between the EU member countries and regions is an important and urgent topic for the economic, scientific and technological strategy of the EU. The issue is important because there are major disparities in the economic development levels of the EU countries and regions. The disparities widened after the accession of the two waves of CEE countries. For example, while in 2000 the ratio of the lowest GDP per capita of a EU-15 member country to the average GDP per capita of the EU-15 was 66%, in 2005, after the accession of the ten countries, the ratio of the lowest GDP per capita to the average GDP per capita of the EU-25 reached 46.6%. After the accession of Romania and Bulgaria, the lowest GDP per capita as against the EU-25 average reached 32%.
The persistence of the disparities and underdevelopment of some EU countries and regions would mean the inconsistency with the very meaning of the European Communities and with the EU strategy, according to which the EU is supposed to become the most important economic and technological power in the world in a predictable period of time, to become the global leader in the economic, scientific, technological and living standard areas. Of course, such a strategy prevents the persistence of disparities and the existence of underdeveloped and poor regions and, also, requires the implementation of policies fully aimed at capitalising the resources of all component countries and regions to achieve their economic and social development. That is why, the EU adopted a firm policy on economic and social cohesion, in order to achieve the real economic convergence of all member countries and regions. From this perspective, it is worth mentioning that all twelve countries of the two accession waves have become cohesion countries, since their GDP per capita has been far below the threshold of 90% of the EU average. Therefore, all these countries satisfy the basic criterion for becoming beneficiaries of the Cohesion Fund for the infrastructure and environment projects. Also, most regions of these countries are eligible for financing from the Structural Funds, since their GDP per capita is below the threshold of 75% of the EU-25 average.
The new member countries have received economic support from the EU since the pre-accession period through special lead-up programmes (PHARE, ISPA, SAPARD, etc.). In the post-accession period, the financial support offered through the new programmes is more consistent as regards the objectives and implementation mechanisms, as well as the size of the funds allocated from the EU multiannual budget (2007-2013). The question “To what extent did these policies influence the real economy convergence?” is difficult to answer by analytical impact assessments, since these policies have not yet produced effects, due to the relatively short time of application.
The clarifying elements in this matter are the overall results of the influence of all factors of convergent growth in each country, determined by means of different factors (usually, computed on long term), which show either the diminution in the inequalities between the set of analysed economies (the evolution of the index concerning the ratio between the level indicators of the economies, dispersion, Gini index, Theil index, etc.), or the cross-section convergence (β-convergence), or, finally, the convergence of the time series, dynamic distribution, etc.. We confine ourselves in this study to the results of the computation of two of the above indicators, which are equally simple and suggestive
(i) The index concerning the ratio between the level indicators (GDP per capita). Relating the level of the GDP per capita of the countries to the average level of the EU for a certain period, one may find general trend of approximation of the development levels of these countries as against the EU average level in the analysed period. Table 2 contains data on the cohesion countries pertaining to the EU-15 Group (Greece, Spain, Portugal) and the countries that joined the EU in 2004 and 2007.

Table 2
The evolution of the index concerning the ratio of the GDP per capita of
the cohesion countries and to the EU-25 average, based on PPP* (1998-2005), percentage

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

Greece

70.4

70.7

72.6

73.5

77.2

81.1

81.9

83.0

Spain

88.8

92.5

92.5

93.2

95.3

97.7

97.3

98.3

Portugal

78.2

80.3

80.6

79.8

79.53

72.8

72.2

70.9

Czech R.

65.3

64.9

63.7

64.9

66.5

67.7

70.04

73.07

Estonia

39.1

38.8

40.7

42.3

45.1

48.4

51.1

55.5

Cyprus

79.3

80.3

81.1

83.1

82.3

80.2

82.3

82.5

Latvia

32.9

34.0

35.3

37.0

38.6

41.0

42.7

46.6

Lithuania

38.5

37.2

38.3

40.3

41.9

45.1

47.6

50.9

Hungary

50.8

51.6

52.7

55.7

58.1

59.4

59.9

61.2

Malta

76.5

77.1

77.6

74.0

74.4

72.8

69.1

69.2

Poland

44.7

45.7

46.7

46.2

46.5

47.0

48.9

49.5

Slovakia

46.9

46.8

47.2

48.6

51.1

52

52.9

55.1

Slovenia

71.5

73.9

72.6

74.0

74.4

76

78.9

80.7

Bulgaria

26.2

26.3

26.7

28.3

28.6

29.6

30.4

32.0

Romania

26.5

25.6

25.1

26.5

28.5

28.5

32.1

32.9

* Purchasing Power Parity.
Source: Based on Eurostat data.

We have related the GDP per capita of each country to the average GDP per capita, computed for 25 countries, although the official computation for the previous financial years was based on the GDP per capita of the cohesion countries related to the average GDP per capita of the EU-15.
The evolution described by the data presented in Table 2 reveals a general trend of approximation to the average index (denoted by 100%) in all cohesion countries. Of course, the evolution of the indices computed for each country reveals the convergence of the real national economies during the pre-accession and post-accession to the EU.
(ii) The variation coefficient of the GDP per capita or the σ-convergence. Frequently used in the economic analysis, the indicator expresses the convergence level as a result of the measurement of the dispersion of the per capita GDP in a group of countries, according to the following formula:
The indicator computation is based on cross-section statistical series (countries), when comparisons in a time sequence are made, and time series (discrete time interval, t and t + T), in order to characterize the evolution (trend) of convergence. When the dispersion decreases in a certain period of time (when the value of the variation coefficient diminishes), convergence takes place.
To characterize the level and evolution of the real convergence process of the EU national economies, we computed the variation coefficient separately, for two groups of countries, EU-25 and EU-10 (the countries which joined the EU in 2004) and for the two alternatives of the GDP per capita expressed in euros: the purchasing power parity (euros-PPP) and market exchange rate (euros). The series cover the period between 1995-2006.
The results of the computation concerning the evolution of the variation coefficient (σ-convergence) are presented in a numerical form in Table 3, in accordance with above alternatives.

Table 3
The numerical evolution of the σ-convergence (the per capita GDP variation coefficient), EU-25 and EU-10

Years

Calculation based on PPP

Calculation based on exchange rate

EU 25

EU 10

EU 25

EU 10

1995

0.44

….

0.71

….

1996

0.43

….

0.68

….

1997

0.42

….

0.65

….

1998

0.41

0.35

0.64

0.81

1999

0.44

0.36

0.66

0.86

2000

0.44

0.34

0.65

0.77

2001

0.42

0.33

0.63

0.67

2002

0.42

0.31

0.63

0.66

2003

0.43

0.28

0.63

0.69

2004

0.43

0.27

0.63

0.64

2005

0.42

0.24

0.62

0.55

2006 *

0.42

0.24

0.62

0.51

*Estimated data.
Source: Based on Eurostat data.

The evolution of the variation coefficients (σ-convergence) computed for the two groups of countries – EU-25 and EU-10 – and on the basis of the PPP is shown in Figure 3.

Figure 7: σ-convergence (variation coefficient) computed on the basis of the per capita GDP (PPP, euro)
Source: Based on Eurostat data.

From the analysis of the level and tendency of the variation coefficients computed for the above alternatives, we draw the following conclusions:
In the case of the ten countries that joined the EU in 2004, the lower level of the variation coefficient means a higher convergence level in relation to the whole of the EU member countries.
The downward trend of the variation coefficient for both alternatives (PPP and exchange rate), more discernible with the 10 countries as against all countries, shows a higher rate of real convergence in this group of countries.
The variation coefficients based on the market exchange rate in the group of ten countries are higher – over two times – than those based on the PPP, which means that the difference among the countries of this group in the standard of living is relatively low and, consequently, the convergence level of these countries expressed in real terms is much higher than that expressed in nominal terms.

Conclusions
Due to the wide gap between Romania and the developed countries and the complexity of the problem as such, the issue of real convergence should be paid special attention. Moreover, it is worth mentioning that, within the theoretical and empirical research in the field, real convergence is the crucial point of the economic growth and enables the researcher to set the objectives, resources and mechanisms; also, it signals the transition of the countries from the periphery (poor) group to the rich one.
To examine the question of the real convergence from different angles, two classes of models have been designed and used: neoclassical and endogenous. In our study we tried to show the limitations of the neoclassical model and, especially, the failure of the assumption concerning the decreasing rate of return on capital. Finding ourselves in opposition to this kind of model, in this study we present the most important features of the endogenous growth model (and derived models) and its capability to include and/or consider the real convergence (divergence) factors.
The latest empirical research aimed at the validation of various convergence hypotheses proves that there is not and it cannot be an alignment of all countries with an “absolute convergence”. What the economic and social reality of the countries and regions confirm is rather the “group convergence”, viewed in its dynamics and in relation to the factors of influence acting within the system. Under the present circumstances, the factor that determines the dynamics of the developed countries is knowledge, in its multiple forms. The knowledge factor determines the higher growth rates of the developed countries, if compared to the poor ones.
As pointed out above, market mechanisms are not able to support the convergence process, especially when there is a wider gap in the development level of the countries and regions. On the contrary, the mechanism stimulates, first, the economic clustering, the formation of development poles, which rather cause wider gaps. Considering these natural processes, the European Union tries to correct the shortcomings of the free market laws by the cohesion policy, besides the sectoral policies, with favourable effects on the economic convergence of the less developed countries with the developed ones.

BIBLIOGRAPHY
1.Abramovitz M., “Catching Up, Forging Ahead, and Falling Behind”, The Journal of Economic History, vol. 46, No. 2, “The Tasks of Economic History” (Jun. 1986), 385-406.
2.Aghion Pilippe, Eve Caroli, Cecilia Garcia-Penalosa, “Inequality and Economic Growth: The Perspective of the New Growth Theories”, Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 37, No. 4 (Dec. 1999), 1615-1660.
3.Allen David, “Coeziunea şi fondurile structurale”, in Hellen Wallace, Willian Wallace and Mark A. Pollack (coord.) Elaborarea politicilor în Uniunea Europeană, (translation), Institutul European din România, 2005.
4.Barro Robert J., “Economic Growth in a Cross-Section of Countries”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 106, No. 2, May 1991, 407-443.
5.Barro Robert J., Xavier Sala-i-Martin, “Convergence”, The Journal of Political Economy, vol. 100, No. 2 (April 1992), 223-251.
6.Bassanini Andrea, Stefano Scarpeta, “The Driving Forces of Economic Growth: Panel Data Evidence for the OECD Countries”, OECD Economic Studies, No. 33, 2001/II.
7.Castro Villaverde José, Indicators of Real Economic Convergence. A Primer, United Nations University, UNU-CRIS E-Working Papers, w-2004/2.
8.Dalgaard Carl-Johan, Jacob Vastrup, “On the Measurement of σ–Convergence”, Economics Letters, 70 (2001) 283-287.
9.Dăianu Dan, “Convergenţa economică. Cerinţe şi posibilităţi”, in Aurel Iancu (coorodinator), Dezvoltarea economică a României. Competitivitatea şi integrarea în Uniunea Europeană, Editura Academiei Române, Bucureşti, 2003.
10.Durlauf St. N., “On the Convergence and Divergence of Growth Rates”, The Economic Journal, vol. 106, No. 437 (June 1996), 1016-1018.
11.Esteban Joan-Maria, Ray Dbraj, “On the Measurement of Polarization”, Econometrica, vol. 62, No. 4, July 1994, p. 819-851.
12.Iancu Aurel, “Problema convergenţei economice”, Oeconomica, nr. 4, 2006.
13.Idu Pompilia, “Instrumentele structurale şi convergenţa statelor în Uniunea Europeană”, Oeconomica, nr. 3/2006.
14.Kutan Ali M., Taner M. Yigit, Convergence of Candidate Countries to the European Union, 2003.
15.Lucas Robert E. Jr., “On the Mechanics of Economic Development” (in “Economic Development and Growth Papers”), Journal of Monetary Economics, 22/1988, 3-42.
16.Manoilescu Mihai, Forţele naţionale productive şi comerţul exterior. Teoria protecţionismului şi a schimbului internaţional, Editura Ştiinţifică şi Enciclopedică, Bucureşti, 1986.
17.Matkowski Zbigniew, Mariusz Prochniak, Economic Convergence in the EU Accession Countries, Warsaw School of Economics.
18.Meeusen Wim, José Villaverde (ed.), Convergence Issues in the European Union, Edward Elgar, UK, 2002.
19.Mihăescu Flavius, “Convergenţa între economiile central şi est-europene”, in Daniel Dăianu and Mugur Isărescu (coordinators), Noii economişti despre tranziţia în România, colecţia Bibliotecii Băncii Naţionale, Bucureşti, 2003.
20.Myrdal G., Economic Theory and Underdeveloped Regions, Duckworth, London, 1957.
21.Pelkmans Jacques, Integrare europeană. Metode şi analiză economică (ed. a II-a) (translation), Institutul European din România, Bucureşti, 2003.
22.Perroux Fr., L’économie du XXe siècle, Paris, P.U.F. , 1969.
23.Perroux Fr., Pour une philosophie du nouveau développement, Paris, Aubier, Les Preses de L’UNESCO, 1981.
24.Prebisch R., “The Periphery in the Global System of Capitalism”, C.E.P.A.L. Review, April, 1981.
25.Puga Diego, “The Rise and Fall of Regional Inequalities”, Centre for Economic Performance, Discussion Paper, No. 314, November 1996, Revised January 1998.
26.Ranis Gustav, Stewart Frances, Ramirez Alejandro, “Economic Growth and Human Development” (in Economic Development and Growth Papers), World Development, vol. 28, No. 6, June 2000.
27.Reiner Martin, “The Impact of the EU’s Structural and Cohesion Funds on Real Convergence in the EU”, NBP Conference, Potential Output and Barriers to Growth, Yalesie Górne, 2003.
28.Romer Paul M., “Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth”, The Journal of Political Economy, vol. 94, No. 5 (October 1986), 1002-1039.
29.Romer Paul M., “Endogenous Technological Change”, The Journal of Political Economy, October 1990, 98,5, AB1/Inform Global.
30.Solow Robert M., “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 70, No. 1 (February 1956), 65-94.
31.Thirlwall A.P., Growth and Development with Special Reference to Developing Economies (sixth ed.), 2001.
32.Wallace Helen, William Wallace and Mark A. Pollack, Elaborarea politicilor în Uniunea Europeană (translation), ediţia a cincea, Institutul European din România, 2005.
33.Zipfel Jacob, Determinants of Economic Growth, Florida State University, 2004.

One Reply to “Real convergence and integration”

  1. Florian Giulau spune:

    Buna,

    Detin o idee inovatoare cu privire la dotarea automobilelor de toate categoriile cu un nou sistem(dispozitiv)care dupa studiile mele nu exista inca.
    La acest sistem gandesc de aprox 4 ani,as fi dorit sa-l inregistrez,sa-l pun in practica dar,nesansa…,m-am hotarat sa cer ajutor,sa gasesc solutii de finantare,chiar si parteneri proiect(mai multe variante).
    Mentionez ca sistemul poate fi aplicat in mai multe feluri,de la cel mai simplu la unul complex(pt auto de lux).
    Astept variante,propuneri,solutii.
    Cu deosebit respect
    Florian Giulau

Lasă un răspuns

Adresa ta de email nu va fi publicată. Câmpurile obligatorii sunt marcate cu *

Acest site folosește Akismet pentru a reduce spamul. Află cum sunt procesate datele comentariilor tale.

scroll to top